Skip to main content

Comparison of pay-for-performance (P4P) programs in primary care of selected countries: a comparative study

Abstract

Background

Pay for performance (P4P) schemes provide financial incentives or facilities to health workers based on the achievement of predetermined performance goals. Various P4P programs have been implemented around the world. There is a question of which model is suitable for p4p implementation to achieve better results. The purpose of this study is to compare pay for performance models in different countries.

Methods

This is a descriptive-comparative study comparing the P4P model in selected countries in 2022. Data for each country are collected from reliable databases and are tabulated to compare their payment models. the standard framework of the P4P model is used for data analysis.

Results

we used the standard P4P model framework to compare pay for performance programs in the primary care sector of selected countries because this framework can demonstrate all the necessary features of payment programs, including performance domains and measures, basis for reward or penalty, nature of the reward or penalty, and data reporting. The results of this study show that although the principles of P4P are almost similar in the selected countries, the biggest difference is in the definition of performance domains and measures.

Conclusions

Designing an effective P4P program is very complex, and its success depends on a variety of factors, from the socioeconomic and cultural context and the healthcare goals of governments to the personal characteristics of the healthcare provider. considering these factors and the general framework of the features of P4P programs are critical to the success of the p4p design and implementation.

Peer Review reports

Introduction

Pay for performance (P4P) schemes – also called performance-based financing or results-based financing schemes – provide financial incentives to health workers or facilities based on the achievement of pre-specified performance targets and have been implemented in health systems across low and middle-income countries (LMICs) [1].

To better align incentives offered with patient and population well-being (or health—one of the well-being arguments), “Pay for performance” schemes have become increasingly common in health care delivery in developing countries. In principle, the idea is simple: use the logic of pay for performance in human resource management [2, 3]. Use of performance incentives in wealthy countries began in earnest during the 1990s with programs that rewarded both process indicators and measures of clinical quality [4]. Examples of performance targets include immunization rates [5, 6] disease screening [7]; adherence to clinical guidelines [8]; and the adoption of case management processes, physician reminder systems, and disease registry systems. Many pay for performance schemes have attempted to directly link payment to quality of care [9].

The premise of P4P is that providers are responsive to financial incentives [10,11,12,13,14] and that each of the commonest payment methods (i.e., fee-for-service, capitation, and salary) is not designed to stimulate good performance and separately creates incentives for undesired behavior. Given that performance measurements have become more accurate over the past two decades, it therefore seems appropriate to use financial incentives explicitly to stimulate improvements in performance [15].

P4P programs are designed to align payments with organizational goals, which give financial incentives to service providers based on performance improvement based on specific criteria, such as quality improvement or cost control or providing services in deprived areas [16,17,18].

A variety of terms have been used interchangeably for pay-for-performance (P4P) incentives, including performance-based incentives (PBI), performance-based pay (PBP), and performance pay (PP). In the broadest sense of the term, P4P can be defined as a payment made to a national or subnational government body, to a health facility or any other healthcare provider, or even to a consumer of health services,3 once predefined results have been attained and verified [19]. This approach targets either the demand or the supply side of health service provision. If the latter is the case, it implies the transfer of financial incentives to health institutions and their staff according to an established ‘performance contract’ with a set of specific ‘performance indicators’ [20].

Pay-for-performance initiatives, if they are effective, can prevent the excessive growth of costs through the prevention and management of chronic diseases while maintaining efficiency, and also these initiatives have the potential to reshape the medical landscape by incentivizing physicians to concentrate on clear goals for common diseases [21].

P4P programs have many differences in definition and implementation. Most of the difference in P4P programs comes from the difference in the definition of indicators and dimensions of performance that are rewarded [22]. P4P has been implemented in the health care system of many countries. In the United States, P4P has been widely implemented in both the private and public sectors. In 2004, the UK introduced P4P in general medical contracts. Other countries such as: Australia, New Zealand, Costa Rica, Haiti, Nicaragua and Taiwan and Turkey have also used similar P4P programs for reimbursement in different programs [22].

All P4P programs include a common set of four basic elements, with a wide variety of choices made within those elements to meet different objectives. the common elements include:

  1. I.

    performance domains and measures;

  2. II.

    basis for reward or penalty;

  3. III.

    nature of the reward or penalty;

  4. IV.

    data reporting and verification [23, 24].

Therefore, there is always the question of which model is suitable to achieve better results for p4p implementation and what are the requirements to achieve the policy goals. The purpose of this study is to compare pay for performance models in different countries.

Method

In this Descriptive-comparative study, pay for performance models in selected countries in 2022 have been compared. The method used for the comparative study was George Brady’s comparative research method. Brady’s model includes four stages: description, interpretation, comparison and comparison [25]. For the division of the research community, the model of the key frameworks of the health care system and their classification was used. Various models have been introduced for the classification of health care systems [26,27,28,29,30,31,32,33]. One of the most complete typologies divides the world’s health systems into 4 groups [34]. Table 1 shows this typology.

Table 1 Typologies of health systems

Based on the above classification, the countries of England, New Zealand, Germany, France, Australia, Canada and the United States: California were selected for comparison in this study. The reason for choosing these countries was to have successful experiences and policies in implementing the P4P pay for performance program in the primary health care sector and to have valid evidence available in the countries.

Required data in scientific databases PubMed, Web of Science, Embase/Medline via Ovid, Cochrane Library, Cochrane Central Registry of Controlled Trials, ProQuest and Scopus, Emerald, as well as the website of the World Health Organization (WHO), the World Bank and OECD library website, were searched using keywords related to payment methods, pay for performance (p4p) and financial incentive in primary care in selected countries. For this reason, in order to identify different P4P programs in selected countries and compare them, the standard framework of the P4P model, which including performance domains and measures, basis for reward or penalty, nature of the reward or penalty and data reporting, was used.

Findings

In this research, the standard framework of the P4P model, which includes 4 elements, which are dimensions and performance indicators, payment strategies, the nature of incentives, and reports, has been used to compare different P4P programs in selected countries. A summary of these elements of P4P model is shown in Table 2. Then, the features of each country’s P4P program are briefly described.

Table 2 Summary of P4P model elements in selected countries

England: quality and outcomes framework (QOF)

The NHS model is widely regarded as the international best practice in delivering health services focused on primary care, and the focus on primary care has helped to contain the cost and efficiency of the system. Almost all GPs in the UK are private entities contracted by primary care organizations under the NHS [23]. Payment to the general practitioner or the family physician is a combination of capitation and pay for performance [35].

The P4P program of the National Health System, known as QOF. QOF established process standards of surveillance for patients with chronic diseases. Performance was measured in terms of successful periodic review and control of conditions such as high blood pressure and diabetes. Performance was rewarded with points for successively high levels of coverage, and each point had a monetary value. The QOF bonuses were paid to each GP practice, thereby incentivizing collective behavior. The effects of the QOF were to improve mean performance and reduce dispersion [36]. In this program, contracts were considered for a 25% increase in the salaries of general practitioners depending on their performance based on quality indicators. The participation of the contracting parties in the QOF program is voluntary [37, 38].

QOF incentives include three main areas known as domains. which include: Clinical domain; Public health domain and quality improvement domain. Each domain includes a set of progress measures, known as indicators, and activities are scored according to their level of success. QOF 2020-21 measures achievement with 68 indicators and a total of up to 567 points can be obtained based on achievement against each indicator.

Clinical domains: includes 57 indicators in 20 clinical fields (such as chronic kidney disease, heart failure, and high blood pressure) with a maximum point of 401.

Public health domains: includes eleven indicators (with a maximum value of 160 points) in five areas of blood pressure, obesity and smoking, vaccination and immunization, and cervical cancer screening.

Quality improvement: includes four indicators (with a maximum value of 74 points) in two areas - Prescription Drug Dependency and Optimizing Access to General Practice [39].

The final payment is adjusted taking into account the workload, local demographics, and the prevalence of chronic diseases in the practice area [35]. Each index has a maximum point value. The value of one QOF point for 2021-22 is £194/83. The points are distributed in such a way that more weight is assigned to the indicators with more workload and more connection with the results [39]. In England, payments are made directly to practices, which are generally groups of 1 to 10 primary care physicians. These payments include 25 to 30% of primary care income [40].

New Zealand: primary health organization performance program (PHO)

New Zealand has a predominantly (about 80%) publicly funded healthcare system, which is mainly funded by general taxation. Funding is devolved to 20 District Health Boards (DHBs) which manage, purchase and/or provide health and disability services for their geographically defined populations. DHBs fund primary care through Primary Health Organizations (PHOs) who contract with GPs and other non-government providers to provide services [41]. General practitioners can join PHO voluntarily. Patient registration in PHO is also not mandatory, but GPs and primary health organizations must have an official registered patient list to be eligible for government subsidies. Patients must register with a general practitioner of their choice. General practitioners act as the gatekeepers of specialized care [42].

The PHO program includes a set of eleven performance indicators in the two areas of chronic patients and vaccination. The program also compiles a set of indicators that are for information only and are not linked to incentive payments. Some indicators are measured separately for “high-need populations” and are rewarded at a higher rate. The high-needs population is defined as the sum of individual registered patients who are Māori (New Zealand’s indigenous population), Pacific Islanders or live in geographic areas of relative socioeconomic deprivation. To strengthen incentives to reduce health disparities, payments for performance are heavily weighted when measuring progress and outcomes among high-needs populations [23, 43].

Fixed payments for most indicators are made to the PHO for each six-month performance period based on the percentage of achievement of each target. Performance pay amounts are based on the following:

  • Population enrolled in PHO for performance period.

  • Progress toward goals for each performance indicator.

  • The amount of payment defined in the PHO contract for each performance period for each registered person.

But total incentive payments account for less than 1% of government primary care spending [23].

Germany: disease management programs (DMP)

The German health system is the Bismarck model. The Ministry of Health pays the resources collected through general tax, insurance tax and private and government insurance premiums to statutory health insurance (SHI) and supervises it. In Germany, the various levels of government play almost no role in directly financing or providing health care. This responsibility is mainly delegated to independent associations in insurance funds and provider associations, which are jointly represented by the Federal Joint Committee [44]. The pay for performance program in Germany is called “Disease Management Programs (DMPs)”, which was introduced in Introduced in 2002, DMPs have since been implemented to position primary care physicians as care coordinators for patients with chronic diseases, using financial incentives to reward better quality of care. Health funds can design their own DMPs. There are differences in the organizational features of DMPs in different regions, as health funds separately define the organizational arrangements and implementation of DMPs. Health funds receive incentives to create DMPs and enroll patients, and in turn provide incentives to physicians [23]. Reimbursement for family physicians who are members of this program is done through a combination of merit payment methods and additional bonuses based on the provision of specific services (such as prevention) [45]. DMPs now cover six major chronic disease areas: diabetes - type I and II, asthma, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease, coronary heart disease, and breast cancer [23].

France: payment for public health objectives (ROSP)

France has compulsory health insurance. Private medical insurance serves to cover additional services and also as excess cost coverage [46]. In France, an experimental measure based on voluntary participation, the Contract for Improvement of Individual Practice (Contrat d’Amélioration des Pratiques Individuelles—CAPI), was launched in 2008 to introduce payment by capitation into the remuneration of general practitioners (GP). In 2011, this measure was extended and became Remuneration based on Public Health Objectives (Rémunération sur Objectifs de Santé Publique—ROSP). ROSP applies to GPs as well as to certain specialists and is regularly updated. Currently, it includes 29 clinical indicators for GPs caring for adult patients. This P4P approach rewards all GPs by providing additional payments based on the level of achievement of ROSP indicators, as assessed by quality indicators. The list of indicators is known, so GPs can consult the expected performance criteria for this additional source of income [47].

Australia: practice incentives program

The insurance system of Australia is National Health Insurance (NHI). The method of payment in the primary care sector in this country is often in the form of FFS (95% of the payment of family physicians) and 5% pay for performance, and there is no capitation payment in this sector [48]. The pay for performance program in This country is called " Practice Incentive Program - PIP” which has been implemented in this country since 1998. The main goal of PIP is to encourage continuous improvement in primary care through financial incentives to support quality care and improve access and health outcomes for patients. And a total of 13 indicators rewards the performance of general practitioners [6].

Canada: family health organizations (FHOs)

Canada has government health insurance specific to each state and the central government supports national programs through Medicare health insurance. The dominant model of primary care across Canada has traditionally been based on solo or group practice physicians, with reimbursement primarily through the submission of FFS bills to provincial health plans for eligible services. Since 1999, the province of Ontario has introduced pay-for-performance incentives for a range of preventive primary care services and some other services provided by family physicians with the aim of improving the quality of patient care. These primary care reforms have been introduced in the form of 4 different models (FHN(2002), FHG(2003), CCM(2005), FHO(2006)) [48, 49].

Family Health Organizations (FHOs), which started in 2006, consist of at least 3 doctors and their financing is based on a combined per capita. Older models of per capita payments were based on age and sex, but in this model, per capita is based on Health care needs or social inequalities are regulated. This model includes 5 main functional areas (influenza vaccination for people over 65 years old, children vaccination, cervical cancer screening (doing pap smear), breast cancer screening (doing mammography), colorectal cancer screening) and 3 activity areas after working hours. Smoking cessation counseling and special care. How to pay incentives If the target threshold is reached, a fixed amount of bonus is paid [49].

United States: California integrated healthcare association physician incentive program

The federal government is responsible for organizing and regulating the health care system in the United States. The financing of the United States is carried out through the collection of general taxes and advance payments. These revenues are allocated to Medicare, Medicaid, and health plans to pay general practitioners (GPs), family physicians, and specialists [50]. The payment mechanism by Medicare and Medicaid, as well as managed care payments, is fee-for-service. Health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and preferred provider organizations (PPOs) pay physicians fee-for-service (FFS) and per capita. Some large HMOs pay physicians a salary [51]. In general, in the United States, insurers and health plans use fee-for-service (FFS), capitation, and fees to pay primary care physicians and specialists. they do. “Pay-for-performance (P4P)” also rarely makes up more than 5% of an America physician’s pay. Out-of-pocket payments (OOP), insurance co-payments, co-payments, and VAT have also increased significantly in recent years for health services [50]. One of the first and perhaps the largest private pay-for-performance (P4P) initiatives was launched by the Integrated Healthcare Association (IHA) in 2001 with Eight health plans representing ten million members were launched in California, USA.

In California, many primary care physicians participate in larger medical organizations (such as multispecialty medical groups and independent practice associations, or IPAs) that contract with health plans on their behalf, and incentive payments to these larger organizations instead of individual physicians [40]. In the California program, there are four domains or functional areas that are recommended for use in P4P, including clinical quality, health information technology, patient experience, and resource utilization, and in It includes a total of 78 indicators. Consolidated performance results are used by health plans to calculate bonuses distributed each year. Each P4P funding plan determines its own methodology for calculating bonus payments to physician groups. IHA proposes a standardized payment method, in which physician groups are scored on the extent of achievement and improvement for each measure [23]. Table 3 shows Payment characteristics of primary care physicians in selected countries and Table 4 shows the Summary of objectives for P4P programs in primary care.

Table 3 Payment characteristics of primary care physicians in selected countries
Table 4 Summary of objectives for P4P programs in primary care

Discussion

Our goal in this study was to compare p4p programs in selected countries using the four main components of the p4p model [22].

The results of this study showed that Most of the difference in P4P programs comes from the difference in the definition of indicators and dimensions of performance to which the reward is awarded.

in general, indicators can be divided into clinical and non-clinical categories. In the category of clinical indicators, which includes prevention of chronic diseases, cancer screening, vaccination, the functional area was common in all P4P programs of the studied countries, although Australia and Germany lacked payment incentives in the field of vaccination and safety. Some countries have set clear goals for the efficiency and optimal use of resources in their p4p program and by using indicators such as Prescription Drug Dependency (England), Quality Prescribing (Australia), Cost- effective prescribing (France), Appropriate Resource Use (United States: California) has addressed this issue.

In the case of non-clinical indicators, performance measures generally reflect the use of information and communication technology (ICT) (i.e., for registration, appointments and other facilities and the use of electronic health records), which in the German indicators There are France, Australia and California.

Increasing access to services is one of the important goals for countries, which is included in the indicators of some countries such as New Zealand, which have specified some indicators aimed at reducing health inequalities separately for “high-needs populations”. Some programs in New Zealand and Australia have tried to reduce inequality in access to services by providing incentives to “deliver services to remote and rural areas”.

Optimizing access to local primary health care is a complex and long-term challenge that has been exacerbated under the pressures of the coronavirus pandemic. A review of access to GPs during the pandemic by Healthwatch England showed that some people are having difficulty booking appointments and accessing treatment [52]. The same England in the latest edition of the QOF-2022 program Optimizing Access to Public Care [52] In addition, Australia and Canada also have incentives in their programs to provide after-hours services, which improves people’s access to primary care and family doctor services.

Overall, the literature highlights that P4P schemes quite often have various positive effects/impacts on intermediate results (inputs, outputs, and less often, outcomes), although many mixed results are reported in the literature. But it is important to bear in mind that not all studies have the same methodological robustness (measurement of effects and consideration of confounding factors) [19]. P4P schemes improve access to and use of health facilities, antenatal and childbirth care dispensed by qualified staff in health facilities, the promotion of family planning activities, the diagnosis and treatment of malaria, HIV, and tuberculosis, and also the implementation of protocols to improve the quality of care [53,54,55,56,57,58,59,60,61,62,63,64,65,66,67].

diversity of this program, it makes it difficult to compare and evaluate, but in general, the selection of indicators In each country, depending on the health priorities of each country, the health and treatment system of that country tries to increase the quality and quantity of those services by providing rewards and incentives, for this reason, indicators related to mental health (England, France, Canada and California) and smoking cessation counseling (England, New Zealand, Canada and California.) are included as indicators in the P4P program. Overall, The studies conducted to design a successful P4P recommend the use of process (intermediate) and result indicators as target criteria [68].

The second element of a P4P program is the basis for reward or penalty, or how achievement against performance indicators is used to determine the level of the incentive payment earned by the provider. The most common options include: the absolute level of the measure (e.g., whether a target was achieved or the number of patients reached); the change in the performance measure (improvement), or how the provider performs against the measure relative to other providers (relative ranking) [69]. In all P4P programs (Except for California), service providers use absolute metrics. In such a way that for each index one target threshold (such as New Zealand and Canada) or a certain point or a fixed amount for the realization of that index (England, Germany, France, Australia) they have considered.

The third common element of P4P programs is the reward or penalty, which may be financial or non- financial, or a combination of both. In all the studied countries, financial incentives were used for encouragement. The effects of financial (bonuses and penalties) and nonfinancial incentives (reputation and peer pressure) are difficult to separate. An important problem with the UK QOF is whether the behavior change was a product of the bonuses paid or the comparative performance measurement that affects the reputation of clinicians and institutions. Those designing P4P incentive systems should ensure that not only can the relative effects of financial and nonfinancial interventions be identified but also that their reforms enhance and do not erode nonpecuniary incentives such as duty, trust, and reputation [36].

Also, the effect of incentives on provider behavior may be influenced by whether payments are made to individual providers or at the group/organizational level. Given the increasingly collaborative forms of care delivery, a collective effort is needed to improve primary care practice. Therefore, holding individual providers accountable for performance is less valid, especially for team-based care. However, at the same time, if incentives are paid at the group level, it is essential that they also reach individual care providers, otherwise they may not influence behavior [70]. There is some evidence that the best focus of incentives is the clinical team. For instance, the NHS incentive scheme for general practitioners in primary care was conditional on practice or team performance and improved activity performance [36]. A counter-argument is that P4P incentive schemes should be focused on the institution rather than the individual physician as that is where the financial risk lies. This is true if institutional budgets are not devolved to clinical teams. If there is budget devolution, teams may respond positively to clinical and financial pressures to improve the efficiency of patient care [36, 71].

In the countries under study, only England, New Zealand have group payments, the United States (California) and Australia also have both individual and group payments.

The next important issue that has been investigated in this study is how to pay general practitioners or family physician in P4P programs. The results of this study show that all selected countries have implemented a combination of payment systems. The “mixed payment system” may reduce the quantity and improve the quality of health care compared to the FFS model and can provide the necessary incentives to achieve the goals of preventive care [72]. An important part of the payment of general practitioners in most of the studied countries, including Canada, New Zealand, England, Germany and United States: California, is the per capita method. These countries adjust per capita by various variables such as age, gender, pregnancy and socio-economic status in the enrolled population. The highest adjustment coefficient per capita has been done in New Zealand, England. The variables used in the per capita adjustment should depend on the health indicators and the socio-economic level of the enrolled population. For example, the capitation payment in England takes into account not only the patient’s age and sex, but also their health status, while New Zealand also takes into account the patient’s use of health services. Capitation based on the patient’s health status and need for care incentivizes physicians to treat harder-to-care patients without requiring additional premiums.

Access to data related to indicators is the fourth component of the P4P program and a main determinant in the design of the P4P program and in improving performance. The report of indicators may be mainly based on claimed data (self-reporting) or electronic registration of the patient’s file. Claims data includes billing codes that physicians, pharmacies, hospitals, and other health care providers send to payers (e.g., insurance companies, Medicare, etc.) [73]. In the studies, only England and New Zealand use data recorded in electronic patient records, and other countries use claims data to report indicators.

Small practices, where the majority of patients still receive care nationally, historically have provided lower quality care—especially solo practices—and may have greater obstacles to improving care because they have lacked the scale and organizational structure to do so. With widespread implementation of EHRs, it is possible that EHR-enabled solo and small group practices will be able to respond to P4P incentives and improve quality [74].

Conclusion

P4P is now widely used in many primary health care systems around the world, but overall, the evidence for the effectiveness of P4P for improving quality of care in primary care is mixed. This is to some extent due to the fact that the P4P schemes used in primary care vary considerably. There are many different schemes that incentivize different aspects of care, in different ways and in different settings. This makes evaluation problematic. By providing a general framework, this study investigated the characteristics of P4P programs along with the conditions and context of different countries. Because the same incentives can lead to very different effects, because their impact depends on a variety of factors, from the socio-economic and cultural context of the health care system and the health care goals of governments to the personal characteristics of the health care provider.

The general framework developed in this study can be useful for target users who are developing and evaluating a P4P application. Careful attention to P4P design is important because poorly designed programs may lead to undesirable provider behavior.

Data availability

The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.

References

  1. Kovacs RJ, Powell-Jackson T, Kristensen SR, Singh N, Borghi J. How are pay-for-performance schemes in healthcare designed in low- and middle-income countries? Typology and systematic literature review. BMC Health Serv Res. 2020;20(1):291.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  2. Lazear EP. Personnel economics. MIT press; 1995.

  3. Lazear EP. The power of incentives. Am Econ Rev. 2000;90(2):410–4.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Rosenthal MB, Fernandopulle R, Song HR, Landon B. Paying for quality: providers’ incentives for quality improvement. Health Aff. 2004;23(2):127–41.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Fairbrother G, Hanson KL, Friedman S, Butts GC. The impact of physician bonuses, enhanced fees, and feedback on childhood immunization coverage rates. Am J Public Health. 1999;89(2):171–5.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  6. Fairbrother G, Siegel MJ, Friedman S, Kory PD, Butts GC. Impact of financial incentives on documented immunization rates in the inner city: results of a randomized controlled trial. Ambul Pediatr. 2001;1(4):206–12.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  7. Rosenthal MB, Frank RG, Li Z, Epstein AM. Early experience with pay-for-performance: from concept to practice. JAMA. 2005;294(14):1788–93.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  8. Roski J, Jeddeloh R, An L, Lando H, Hannan P, Hall C, et al. The impact of financial incentives and a patient registry on preventive care quality: increasing provider adherence to evidence-based smoking cessation practice guidelines. Prev Med. 2003;36(3):291–9.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  9. Ryan AM, Krinsky S, Kontopantelis E, Doran T. Long-term evidence for the effect of pay-for-performance in primary care on mortality in the UK: a population study. The Lancet. 2016;388(10041):268–74.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Dudley RA, Miller RH, Korenbrot TY, Luft HS. The impact of financial incentives on quality of health care. Milbank Q. 1998;76(4):649–86.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  11. Gosden T, Forland F, Kristiansen I, Sutton M, Leese B, Giuffrida A et al. Capitation, salary, fee-for‐service and mixed systems of payment: effects on the behaviour of primary care physicians. Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews. 2000(3).

  12. Gosden T, Forland F, Kristiansen IS, Sutton M, Leese B, Giuffrida A, et al. Impact of payment method on behaviour of primary care physicians: a systematic review. J Health Serv Res Policy. 2001;6(1):44–55.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Hillman AL, Pauly MV, Kerstein JJ. How do financial incentives affect physicians’ clinical decisions and the financial performance of health maintenance organizations? N Engl J Med. 1989;321(2):86–92.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. Town R, Wholey DR, Kralewski J, Dowd B. Assessing the influence of incentives on physicians and medical groups. Med care Res Rev. 2004;61(3suppl):80S–118S.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Eijkenaar F. Key issues in the design of pay for performance programs. Eur J Health Econ. 2013;14(1):117–31.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  16. Chang RE, Lin SP, Aron DC. A pay-for-performance program in Taiwan improved care for some diabetes patients, but doctors may have excluded sicker ones. Health Aff. 2012;31(1):93–102.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Kolozsvári LR, Orozco-Beltran D, Rurik I. Do family physicians need more payment for working better? Financial incentives in primary care. Aten Primaria. 2014;46(5):261–6.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  18. Portela MC. [The british pay-for-performance in primary health care]. Cadernos de saude publica. 2014;30(1):5–7.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  19. Mathonnat J, Pelissier A. How a Results-Based Financing approach can contribute to the health Sustainable Development Goals-Policy-oriented lessons: what we know, what we need to know and don’t yet know. FERDI Working Paper; 2017.

  20. Kalk A, Paul FA, Grabosch E. Paying for performance’ in Rwanda: does it pay off? Tropical medicine & international health. TM & IH. 2010;15(2):182–90.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Locke RG, Srinivasan M. Attitudes toward pay-for-performance initiatives among primary care osteopathic physicians in small group practices. J Am Osteopath Assoc. 2008;108(1):21–4.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  22. Kuo RN, Chung K-P, Lai M-S. Effect of the pay-for-performance program for breast cancer care in Taiwan. J Oncol Pract. 2011;7(3S):e8s–e15s.

  23. Cashin C, Chi Y-L, Smith P, Borowitz M, Thomson S. Paying for performance in health care. Implications for health system performance and accountability. 2015.

  24. SORBERO ME, DAMBERG CL, SHAW R, TELEKI SS, LOVEJOY SL, DECRISTOFARO AH et al. Assessment of pay-for-performance options for Medicare physician services. Final Report. 2006:May 2006.

  25. Aghazadeh A. Comparative education. Tehran: Samt; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  26. The Reform of. Health care: a comparative analysis of seven OECD countries / Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Paris: O.E.C.D.; 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Blank RH, Burau V. Comparing health policy: an assessment of typologies of health systems. Comparing Health Policy. 2010:1000–17.

  28. Field MG. The concept of the “health system” at the macrosociological level. Social Sci Med (1967). 1973;7(10):763–85.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  29. Frenk J, Donabedian A. State intervention in medical care: types, trends and variables. Health Policy Plann. 1987;2(1):17–31.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  30. Hollingsworth JR, Hage J, Hanneman R. State intervention in medical care. State intervention in Medical Care. Cornell University Press; 2019.

  31. Navarro V. Why some countries have national health insurance, others have national health services, and the US has neither. Soc Sci Med. 1989;28(9):887–98.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Roemer MI. The Countries. Vol. 1 of National Health Systems of the World. New York: Oxford University Press; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Terris M, Cornely PB, Daniels HC, Kerr LE. The case for a national health service. Am J Public Health. 1977;67(12):1183–5.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  34. Lee S-Y, Chun C-B, Lee Y-G, Seo NK. The National Health Insurance system as one type of new typology: the case of South Korea and Taiwan. Health Policy. 2008;85(1):105–13.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Mohammadibakhsh R, Aryankhesal A, Jafari M, Damari B. Family physician model in the health system of selected countries: a comparative study summary. J Educ health promotion. 2020;9:160.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Maynard A. The powers and pitfalls of payment for performance. Health Econ. 2012;21(1):3–12.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  37. Roland M. Linking physicians’ pay to the quality of care—a major experiment in the United Kingdom. Mass Medical Soc; 2004. pp. 1448–54.

  38. Santos R, Barsanti S, Seghieri C. Pay for performance in primary care: the use of administrative data by health economists. Data-Driven Policy Impact Evaluation: Springer, Cham; 2019. p. 313 – 32.

  39. NHS. Quality and Outcomes Framework guidance for 2022/23. Wwwenglandnhsuk. England; 2022.

  40. McDonald R, Roland M. Pay for performance in primary care in England and California: comparison of unintended consequences. The Annals of Family Medicine. 2009;7(2):121–7.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  41. World Health Organization. Regional Office for the Western Pacific. (2014). New Zealand health system review. WHO Regional Office for the Western Pacific. https://apps.who.int/iris/handle/10665/207738.

  42. Gauld R. The New Zealand health care system. International Profiles of Health Care Systems New York. 2020:149–58.

  43. Buetow S. Pay-for‐performance in New Zealand primary health care. J Health Organ Manag. 2008;22(1):36–47.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  44. Sanchez MA, Sanchez S, Bouazzi L, Peillard L, Ohl-Hurtaud A, Quantin C. Does the implementation of pay-for-performance indicators improve the quality of healthcare? First results in France. Front public health. 2023;11:1063806. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpubh.2023.1063806.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  45. Rosemann T, Wensing M, Rueter G, Szecsenyi J. Referrals from general practice to consultants in Germany: if the GP is the initiator, patients’ experiences are more positive. BMC Health Serv Res. 2006;6(1):1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Chevreul K, Berg Brigham K, Durand-Zaleski I, Hernandez-Quevedo C, France. Health System Review. Health systems in transition. 2015;17(3):1-218, xvii.

  47. Sanchez MA, Sanchez S, Bouazzi L, Peillard L, Ohl-Hurtaud A, Quantin C. Does the implementation of pay-for-performance indicators improve the quality of healthcare? First results in France. Front public health. 2023;11:1063806.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  48. Tikkanen R, Osborn R, Mossialos E, Djordjevic A, Wharton G. International profiles of health care systems. Commonw Fund. 2020.

  49. Rudoler D, Laporte A, Barnsley J, Glazier RH, Deber RB. Paying for primary care: a cross-sectional analysis of cost and morbidity distributions across primary care payment models in Ontario Canada. Soc Sci Med. 2015;124:18–28.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  50. Rice T, Rosenau P, Unruh LY, Barnes AJ, Saltman RB, Van Ginneken E et al. United States of America: health system review. 2013.

  51. Manchikanti L, Hirsch JA. Medicare physician payment rules for 2011: a primer for the neurointerventionalist. J neurointerventional Surg. 2011;3(4):399–402.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Quality. and Outcomes Framework guidance for 2022/23. NHS, England.

  53. Kalk A, Paul FA, Grabosch E. Paying for performance’in Rwanda: does it pay off? Tropical Med Int Health. 2010;15(2):182–90.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Van Herck P, De Smedt D, Annemans L, Remmen R, Rosenthal MB, Sermeus W. Systematic review: effects, design choices, and context of pay-for-performance in health care. BMC Health Serv Res. 2010;10(1):1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Basinga P, Gertler PJ, Binagwaho A, Soucat AL, Sturdy J, Vermeersch CM. Effect on maternal and child health services in Rwanda of payment to primary health-care providers for performance: an impact evaluation. The Lancet. 2011;377(9775):1421–8.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Publications WB. The World Bank Annual Report 2013: World Bank Publications; 2013.

  57. Miller G, Babiarz KS. Pay-for-performance incentives in low-and middle-income country health programs. 2013.

  58. Bonfrer I, Soeters R, Van de Poel E, Basenya O, Longin G, van de Looij F, et al. Introduction of performance-based financing in Burundi was associated with improvements in care and quality. Health Aff. 2014;33(12):2179–87.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Gertler PJ, Giovagnoli PI. Rewarding provider performance to enable a healthy start to life: evidence from Argentina’s Plan Nacer. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. 2014(6884).

  60. Chimhutu V, Lindkvist I, Lange S. When incentives work too well: locally implemented pay for performance (P4P) and adverse sanctions towards home birth in Tanzania-a qualitative study. BMC Health Serv Res. 2014;14:1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Helland J, Mæstad O. Experiences with results-based payments in Norwegian Development Aid. Evaluation Department Report; 2015.

  62. Kandpal E. Completed impact evaluations and emerging lessons from the Health results Innovation Trust Fund learning portfolio. Washington, DC: The World Bank; 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Lannes L. Improving health worker performance: the patient-perspective from a PBF program in Rwanda. Soc Sci Med. 2015;138:1–11.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  64. Sun X, Liu X, Sun Q, Yip W, Wagstaff A, Meng Q. The impact of a pay-for‐performance scheme on prescription quality in rural China. Health Econ. 2016;25(6):706–22.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  65. Nimpagaritse M, Korachais C, Roberfroid D, Kolsteren P, Zine Eddine El Idrissi MD, Meessen B. Measuring and understanding the effects of a performance based financing scheme applied to nutrition services in Burundi—a mixed method impact evaluation design. Int J Equity Health. 2016;15(1):1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Witter S, Fretheim A, Kessy FL, Lindahl AK. Paying for performance to improve the delivery of health interventions in low-and middle‐income countries. Cochrane database of systematic reviews. 2012(2).

  67. Renmans D, Holvoet N, Orach CG, Criel B. Opening the ‘black box’of performance-based financing in low-and lower middle-income countries: a review of the literature. Health Policy Plann. 2016;31(9):1297–309.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Van Herck P, De Smedt D, Annemans L, Remmen R, Rosenthal MB, Sermeus W. Systematic review: Effects, design choices, and context of pay-for-performance in health care. BMC Health Serv Res. 2010;10(1):247.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  69. Scott IA. Pay for performance programs in Australia: a need for guiding principles. Aust Health Rev. 2008;32(4):740–9.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  70. Berenson RA, Pronovost PJ, Krumholz HM. Achieving the potential of health care performance measures. Timely Anal Immed Health Pol. 2013;2013:2.

    Google Scholar 

  71. Cromwell J, Trisolini MG, Pope GC, Mitchell JB, Greenwald LM. Pay for performance in health care: methods and approaches. RTI Press; 2011.

  72. Kralj B, Kantarevic J. Quality and quantity in primary care mixed-payment models: evidence from family health organizations in Ontario. Can J Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique. 2013;46(1):208–38.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Wilson J, Bock A. The benefit of using both claims data and electronic medical record data in health care analysis. Optum Insight. 2012;1:1–4.

    Google Scholar 

  74. Bardach NS, Wang JJ, De Leon SF, Shih SC, Boscardin WJ, Goldman LE, et al. Effect of pay-for-performance incentives on quality of care in small practices with electronic health records: a randomized trial. JAMA. 2013;310(10):1051–9.

    CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

Thanks to the Research Deputy of the Faculty of Health and management, Mashhad University of Medical Sciences.

Funding

This study has been funded and supported by Mashhad University of Medical Sciences. (MUMS). grant no: 4000510.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

SJ analyzed and interpreted data, completed the first draft of the paper, and incorporated co-author feedback. MY analyzed and interpreted data; drafted portions of the paper, table, and figures; and provided critical feedback on drafts of the manuscript. HE designed the analysis, analyzed and interpreted data, and provided critical feedback on drafts of the manuscript. AT and ST contributed to framing and provided critical feedback on drafts of the manuscript. EH analyzed and interpreted data and provided critical feedback on drafts of the manuscript. AA analyzed and interpreted data and provided critical feedback on drafts of the manuscript. All authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mehdi Yousefi.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent to publication

Not applicable.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/zero/1.0/) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated in a credit line to the data.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jamili, S., Yousefi, M., pour, H.E. et al. Comparison of pay-for-performance (P4P) programs in primary care of selected countries: a comparative study. BMC Health Serv Res 23, 865 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1186/s12913-023-09841-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s12913-023-09841-6

Keywords